Interesting questions and ideas, Scot. I haven’t read Drumm’s dissertation, so I can’t comment on his ideas. But I do have some questions for you. First, if we’re going to talk about the ‘nature of power’, how do you define power?
Blair,
I apologize for not responding earlier. For some reason, I did not see you had replied.
I know that CasP theory typically defines “power” as “confidence in obedience;” however, I find this definition assumes too much about the awareness of both ruler and ruled regarding their respective status. Accordingly, I prefer defining the term a bit closer to how proto-liberals (e.g., Locke, Jefferson, and Paine) defined it, which is the antonym of how they understood freedom (from the power of others). The power we are concerned with is the arbitrary, coercive power of an individual to subjugate the agency/will of another. Thus, to me, power is necessarily coercive, and I don’t care if coercion is applied directly through violence or the threat of violence, or indirectly through the denial of access to resources necessary to exist.
If your choices are controlled by another, you are not free. You are, effectively, a slave.
Second, what is the ‘nature of money’?
Historically, money has been identified as having three major functions: (1) acting as a unit of account; (2) acting as a medium of exchange; and (3) acting as store of value.
One of my key takeaways from Colin’s book (as he likes to call his dissertation) is modern money transplanted the “store of value” function from money (bimetallic coins with intrinsic wealth value based on the amount of the particular metal the coins contained) to capital (tallies of wealth value maintained in accounting books). Severing wealth from money allowed wealth to be “hoarded” without hoarding money, a problem that prevented capitalist economies from manifesting in the first place due to the counter-intuitively negative effects of peace (preparing for the next war required hoarding the wealth required to fund it and/or the crown taxing the hoarded wealth of the elites). This hoarding/taxing dynamic led to distrust between the king and his elites, which ultimately led to the solution of modern money as first instituted by the Bank of England.
Modern money capitalizes the future labor of the debtor. Hence, all modern money begins as indentured servitude. Ancient money and wealth, on the other hand, was grounded in existing metal, which is why hoarding wealth withdrew money from circulation, depressing the economy, at least as we measure it today with GDP. Ancient money enforced a zero-sum game because it had to. Modern money enforces exponential growth because it has to.
My own take is that focusing on money itself is a bit of a distraction. My view is that money is nothing but a quantification of property rights. Part of the development of capitalism involved making the unit of quantification progressively more abstract. But really, the abstraction has been there all along. There is nothing in gold that makes it valuable. But it is convenient (for the human mind) to give a unit a physical dimension.
I disagree. As Colin says, money makes a difference. Market exchanges occurred before there was “money,” but the the commensurating commodity itself, e.g., a particular weight of silver or wheat, did all the work. For some reason, forever lost to the sands of time, somebody introduced money as a substitute for the underlying commensurating commodity. (Note: Colin will insist that it was Lydian kings who introduced money, but, like most ancient historians, he is far too credulous of ancient historians, who are famous liars). In hindsight, it is easy to see that the “spread” between the nominal value (Colin’s “inside option”) and the intrinsic value (Colin’s “outside option”) of coined money created a tax that accrued to the king and his cronies, but I don’t believe that’s how ancient money began because the outside option always existed. It was the inside option that was new, and the king could have just as easily taxed the bullion as the money. Thus, ancient money, like modern money, solved a problem. What was that problem? I don’t know, but I think it most likely relates to securing the loyalty of a standing army (specifically, the Neo-Assyrian army). By paying soldiers in a way that gave them more wealth in the state they served then could be gained by the intrinsic metal value of the means of payment, it made it less likely for the soldiers to switch sides.
The more interesting element of money, at least for me, is the progressive expansion of property rights — the ability to own and therefore quantify anything.
Credit money is the primary mechanism for transferring power from the ruled to the rulers. The ruled need money to live. The rulers condition the availability of money on a debtor’s servitude, and whether the debtor is among the rulers or the ruled, the ruled ultimately pay. Money is not at all based on the expansion of property rights because no property is exchanged, only credit for a promise of servitude (among CasPers, Di Muzio gets this best, I think). Capital is based on the expansion of the money supply (debt) and the expansion of property rights (equity). CasP metrics focus on equity, which creates a blindspot regarding debt. CasP needs to understand money, debt and equity (and the relationship between all three) to be a comprehensive theory.
To get back to the question of power, I agree that power is essentially the same everywhere, in that it is simply the ability to influence others. But what is not constant is the ideology that motivates the followers.
Ideologies are, always and everywhere, created by, and for the benefit of, the rulers. What is particularly insidious about the liberal/capitalist ideology is the ruled have been duped into believing they are free. The reality is that you are not free in a liberal society unless you are free from the Market.
I, like Marx and Locke, believe in the promise of what today is known as liberal ideology– freedom from coercive power. That is what I would like to see, more than anything else, but even what that means is subject to interpretation. For example, Nitzan believes in the idea of an autonomous democracy, but I believe that such a democracy imposes too much work from the vast majority of people, who just want to vibrate in their happy place, which ought to be okay. As long as those who care about ruling are not allowed to exploit (impose arbitrary, coercive power over) those who don’t, then everything should work out.