- This topic has 1 reply, 2 voices, and was last updated November 7, 2021 at 11:43 pm by .
-
Topic
-
I was following up on some interesting work done by an economist named Richard A. Warner, and I came across the following article he co-authored with Kang-Soek Lee:
Bottom line: Lee and Werner reject the assertion that loose monetary policy (low interest rates) spurs economic growth, finding that interest rates and GDP growth are positively correlated (e.g., low interest rates correspond to low GDP growth).
They intuit that loose monetary policy results in “unproductive” borrowing that does not result in GDP growth (e.g., borrowing money for stock buy-backs or leveraging a hedge fund).
Regardless, to me this article suggests that the cost of capital/credit plays an important role in differential accumulation and sabotage that is not fully accounted for by CasP’s depth/breadth regime analysis.
The detailed conclusions of the paper are as follows:
Our empirical findings on the correlation and statistical causation can be summarised as follows: (1) Nominal GDP growth is highly and positively correlated with short and long-term rates in all four countries; (2) Nominal GDP growth Granger-causes long-term rates in all countries examined, whereas the opposite holds only in one country (Germany, with two-directional causality); (3) Nominal GDP growth Granger causes short-term rates in all four countries, whereas the opposite holds only in one country (the US, where a strong two-directional causality is found).
The data suggests overall that statistical causality runs from economic growth to long-term interest rates. Nominal GDP growth provides information on future interest rates better than interest rates inform us about future nominal GDP growth.
Our empirical findings reject the canonical view that interest rates somehow affect economic growth, and in an inverse manner. To the
contrary, long-term and short-term interest rates follow the trend of nominal GDP, in the same direction, in all countries examined. This suggests that markets are not in equilibrium and the third factor driving GDP growth is a quantity – as shown by Werner (1997, 2012a) in the case of Japan (namely, the quantity of bank credit creation for the real economy – i.e., for GDP transactions, as the Quantity Theory of Credit postulates; Werner, 2013a).Herman Daly wrote in 1991:
“Environmental economics, as it is taught in universities and practiced in government agencies and development banks, is overwhelmingly microeconomics. The theoretical focus is on prices, and the big issue is how to internalize external environmental costs so as to arrive at prices that reflect full social marginal opportunity costs. Once prices are right, the environmental problem is ‘solved’”
(Daly, 1991, 255).
In this paper the validity of this focus on prices was put to the test. We examined the central price variable, the interest rate. All schools of equilibrium economics (which is most 19th, 20th and 21st century economics, from classical, Marxist, neoclassical and Keynesian to
monetarist, new classical, post-Keynesian, neo-Wicksellian and Austrian, and likely over 95% of all publications in economics) agree
that lower interest rates stimulate economic growth, while higher interest rates slow it. This sums up ‘the law and the prophets’ in equilibrium economics, across the alleged ideological divides. We presented the first serious test of this claim, by carefully examining over half a century of data on four major economies (the US, the UK, Japan and Germany, representing not only much of world GDP during half a century, but also different ‘varieties of capitalism’). Out of the ensuing 8 cases (long and short rates in four countries) we found the hypothesis that interest rate levels cause economic growth rejected in 6 out of 8 cases. The alternative hypothesis that economic growth determines interest rate levels is supported in 8 out of 8 cases. Concerning correlation, we found that despite allowing for 2 years of leads and lags, the hypothesis that interest rates are inversely correlated with economic growth is rejected in 8 out of 8 cases. Instead, we found that interest rates are positively correlated with economic growth in 8 of 8 cases.The central claim that unites the theory-driven deductive equilibrium economics (virtually all of macro-economics as taught at university and commonly discussed in public discourse) is without merit. The alternative view is the notion of pervasive rationing (Muellbauer and Portes, 1978; Werner, 2005), which implies the dominance of quantities over prices (Werner, 2005). That is consistent with the half century of data examined here.
There are many implications of our findings. If rationing is more frequent than assumed, quantities are of paramount importance in
economics, not prices. This paper provides impetus to the research agenda emphasising quantities in general, including resource constraints and therefore the environmental dimension in particular.If interest rates do not move the economy, what does? If not the price of money, then its quantity? Werner (1997, 2015), Lyonnet and
Werner (2012), Ryan-Collins et al. (2016) and Bermejo Carbonell and Werner (2018) have found that nominal GDP growth and interest rates are driven by a common third factor, the quantity of credit creation ‘for the real economy’, which beats interest rates and standard monetary aggregates in predicting and explaining nominal GDP growth in various empirical tests, including in Japan, Spain and the UK – just as the Quantity Theory of Credit postulates (Werner, 1992, 1997).—
- You must be logged in to reply to this topic.